Metropolitan
Museum of Art
Adriaen
Isenbrant: Man Weighing Gold (detail), circa 1515–1520
Jeff Madrick
In his
celebrated book Capital in the 21st Century, Thomas Piketty notes that Napoleon
justified concentrations of wealth and high levels of inequality in France
because, he claimed, the nation was a meritocracy. If you worked hard and had
talent, you could rise—even back then.
Such
inflated claims about income mobility have long been the refuge of the
privileged at the top of the distribution of wealth. The American dream is of
course built on this central assertion. Since the beginning of the year,
however, the powerful findings of Piketty and other economists have entered
mainstream debate as never before, challenging long-held assumptions that
America is a meritocracy. Bringing into focus how lopsided the income
distribution is, these findings have not only shown that inequality is
widespread. They have also demonstrated that there is relatively little
opportunity for those in the lower quintiles of earners to move up to a higher
bracket.
Traditionally,
economic conservatives have maintained that inequality is fine as long as
income mobility is robust. So what if a few people make huge fortunes; everyone
else has a fair chance at the opportunity to do so. But these days, even
important members of the Republican Party, the traditional bastion of America
privilege, have given up on this argument.
Economic
data gathered since the early 2000s have shown conclusively that American
social mobility is low and has been so for half a century—indeed, it is
considerably lower than the nation’s supposedly stultified European
competitors, where social safety nets are much larger and taxes much higher.
Among the most impressive of the new work is a comprehensive study, led by Raj
Chetty of Harvard and Emmanuel Saez of Berkeley, among others, published this
January. It shows that income mobility has remained at roughly the same low
levels since the 1970s.
The way
income mobility is generally measured is to determine whether children born to
parents in one quintile of earners—say, the bottom 20 percent—move to the next
quintile, and then up and beyond. According to the Harvard-Berkeley study, only
8.4 percent of children born in 1971 to parents in the bottom fifth rose to the
top fifth as adults, a proportion that grew only slightly, to 9 percent, for
those born in 1986. More sobering, children born into the second quintile from
the bottom are now doing worse. In 1971, such a child had a 17.7 percent chance
to move to a higher quintile; for those born in 1986, the odds were only 13.8
percent, or less than one in seven.
These
figures—measuring what we think of as traditional or “relative” income
mobility—provide a stark picture of how fluid economic opportunity is and many
progressives have flocked to them. In recent weeks, many commentators have
decried the unequal distribution of income and wealth and argued that we should
take steps to limit inequality at the top and make it easier for people to
climb the ladder.
But for
every poor kid who rises to the top fifth in income, roughly speaking, someone
must fall out of the top fifth. And the proportion of those who rose was
probably never robust, even in the nineteenth century. What matters still more,
then, is “absolute” mobility: the degree to which the economy can produce
rising wages for all.
The
American dream should be built on expanding opportunities for the entire
society, which can only come about if average real wages go up. Earning more
than your parents is as much or even more a result of the rise of wages after
inflation across the economy as it is a reflection of income mobility. In other
words, if you are born into the bottom quintile but real wages rise, you will
likely exceed your parents’ income even if you remain in that quintile.
Such real
incomes rose throughout the nineteenth and twentieth centuries in America, but
they rose especially fast in the twenty to thirty years after World War II. As
Isabel Sawhill of Brookings pointed out in one of the finest studies of income
mobility, made with the Pew Foundation five years ago,
from 1947
to 1973, the rate of growth of the typical family’s income was unusually rapid,
roughly doubling in a generation’s time. However, since 1973 the increase over
a generation’s time has been much smaller, about 20 percent.
Since the
Great Recession, there has been even less growth. Such historic comparisons of
family income can be tricky. On the one hand, families tend to have fewer
children than they did a generation ago, but on the other, the rapid growth of
households with two working parents creates additional childcare costs. The
distribution of family income is also skewed as more children are born to unwed
mothers, who don’t benefit from two incomes. According to Sawhill, none of this
overturns “the basic conclusion that family income growth has slowed.”
The New
York Times just published calculations based on the detailed data collected by
the Luxembourg Income Study that show middle class incomes in America are now
lower than in some other nations. And Sawhill shows that out of every three
adults who were children in 1968, one is earning less than his or her parents
did. That latter number is troublingly big, and since the Great Recession it
has probably risen.
What we
now know is that we can’t rely on income mobility to solve these problems.
Because there has been growth, if modest compared to earlier times, about two
out of three children are doing better than their parents. But many of them are
not doing much better—about half of this group remain in the same quintile they
were born into. Indeed, rising income inequality also makes it harder to move
from one quintile to another: the rungs on the ladder are farther apart.
Consider
that we now know 42 percent of those born into the bottom fifth of earners will
remain there, and another 42 percent will rise only to the next two levels. At
the same time, 39 percent born into the top will remain at the top, and 23
percent will fall but only to the next level down.
Yet for
all this, the problem of inequality is an inadequate description of the
situation. Inequality has traditionally meant that incomes at the top grow
faster than the next category down, which in turn grow faster than the next
category, and so on. All categories can grow to some extent. As has been
apparent to economists for several years, however, this is no longer the case.
We now have stagnating incomes for a large majority of Americans and runaway
incomes at the very top—especially the top tenth of the top one percent. This
is not so much “inequality” as a complete lack of growth for much of the
country. And this is what the nation should focus on.
The
authors of the recent Harvard-Berkeley study provide some clues about how to
proceed. They find both relative and absolute mobility differs by cities. Those
in the Southeast have generally low mobility rates while those in the mountain
and western states high rates, for example. In urban areas with more healthy
economies, like San Francisco, Seattle, and Salt Lake City, the poor are less
segregated, the quality of education is higher, and there are fewer unwed
mothers. But these conditions cannot be readily duplicated elsewhere.
The main
lesson is that a combination of social policies and growth policies are needed
that aim at producing rising wages for all. They could include a higher minimum
wage, child allowances, and educational programs for the young about the
disadvantages of early pregnancies.
But they
should also include serious stimulus measures by the federal government,
including a recognition that deficits are now low enough and that further
austerity is unnecessary. In particular, government spending programs should
aim to sustain decent income levels through unemployment insurance, expanded
earned income and child tax credits, and outright cash allowances. The
government should also aim at foundational projects that facilitate long-term
economic growth, including intelligent and aggressive expansion of
transportation, and Internet infrastructure.
There is
simply no escaping the central fact that the welfare of Americans depends on
faster economic growth. Progressives and conservatives should agree on this.
This economic recovery so far has been slow. Debt overhangs from the mortgage
crisis explain part of it, but the lack of appropriate policy to offset the
ramifications of the financial and housing crashes are inexcusable. Efforts to
enhance income mobility alone cannot be the answer.
April 24,
2014, 5:57 p.m.
No comments:
Post a Comment